Ferries For The San Francisco Bay Area; New Paradigms From
New Technologies
Chris Barry (Member), Bryan Duffty (Member), and Paul Kamen (Visitor)
Presented at the joint meeting of the Society of Naval Architects and
Marine Engineers, Asilomar, Pacific Grove, California
May 31 2002
Appendix A:
A Detailed Plan for a Berkeley to San Francisco Ferry Service
"Even
a journey of a thousand miles begins with a two-hour schlep to the
airport"
Chinese proverb
(slightly modified)
Figure A-1
Jacob's Landing in the late 19th
Century
Background
Ferry
service from Berkeley to San Francisco began in 1851 when James H. Jacobs built
the wharf at the mouth of Strawberry Creek, and ended in 1956 when the last
scheduled ferry left the end of the Berkeley Municipal Pier. The Bay Bridge
(1936), the proliferation of the private auto, and finally transbay BART
service (1973) all made ferries redundant and obsolete.
Temporary
ferry services have operated during a BART strike (1979) and during the closure
of the Bay Bridge following the Loma Prieta earthquake (1989).
But the
boats were old and slow, the docking arrangements inside the Berkeley Marina
were time consuming and the ridership could not be maintained.
Even in the
weeks following the Loma Prieta earthquake with the Bay Bridge closed, there
were never more than 500 morning commuters taking the ferry.
What the ferry can and cannot do
It is
recognized that a Berkeley ferry is not likely to significantly alleviate
vehicular congestion or improve regional air quality. It is primarily an
amenity and an alternative to other forms of private and public transportation.
However, because it will be possible to operate this ferry service without
significant public subsidy, funds will not be redirected from other modes of
public transportation. The probable lack of measurable impact on Bay Area
traffic congestion is therefore not a valid argument against the ferry service
proposed here.
What the
Berkeley ferry will do is increase mobility. Ferry service has become desirable
again because of the chronic congestion on the Bay Bridge and the saturation of
the BART system. For example, for those who do not live within walking distance
of a BART station, after about 8:00 am when the BART parking lots fill up there
are essentially no options but to drive to San Francisco. Crossing the bridge
by car on a weekday morning (or Saturday evening) is unpleasant and very slow,
and parking is expensive. The loss of the ability to move about the inner Bay
Area freely and comfortably has a high economic cost, and ultimately adds to
the pressure for suburban sprawl.
The Boat
Design evolution
begins with the selection of the number of passengers. See figure A-2, which
shows passengers per crew as a function of number of passengers. The first
local maximum, at 149 passengers, is chosen as the only economical point that
is consistent with modest ridership projections. Also, a significant increase
in first cost is incurred at larger capacities due to more rigorous construction
standards imposed by the Coast Guard for vessels carrying 150 passengers or
more.
Figure
A-2 Passengers per crew v. number of
passengers
The Coast
Guard allows a crew of two for a single deck design, but one additional crew is
required for each additional passenger deck. Therefore a single-deck design is
strongly indicated. There is also motivation for large deck area to accommodate
bicycles, dogs and possibly electric scooters.
Speed is
determined by the distance and the required transit time. 17 knots is
sufficient for a single boat to provide hourly service over the 5.6 mile route,
with 20 minute transit time and ten minute turn-around at the terminals. 18
knots is the specified service speed, to allow for adverse tides.
Figure A-3
shows the sensitivity of required speed to terminal turn-around time. This
implies multiple boarding points, whether docked bow-in or side-tied, to facilitate
very rapid loading and unloading.
Figure
A-3: Required speed and power v.
turnaround time
The ride
must be quiet and comfortable, with vessel motions comparable to larger vessels.
The seating arrangement should be spacious, allowing most passengers the choice
of a work table or a good view.
Fuel
efficiency must be extremely high and emissions must be extremely low.
To
summarize the primary requirements:
Single-level
passenger area
Large deck
area
Modest
speed
Spacious
interior
Ride
comfort
Fuel
efficiency
All these
requirements point to a multihull with very long and very slender hulls
operating in displacement mode.
An asymmetrical
proa configuration is attractive because of the longer overall length for
reduced motions and better fuel efficiency, and for reduced cost due to the consolidation
of machinery into a single engine and driveline. However, figure A-4 shows that
in the power range under consideration, there is no significant machinery cost
saving available by using one large propulsion system instead of two smaller
ones. This is because the economies of scale have made diesel engine in the 300
hp range very inexpensive compared to smaller and larger power ratings.
Figure
A-4 Cost per brake horsepower (BHP) v.
horsepower
The vessel
proposed is a 149-passenger single-deck catamaran (with seats for 180) designed
to operate at a speed of 18 knots. It will be powered by two diesel engines of
approximately 350 hp each and operate with a crew of two.
18 knots is
relatively slow by modern standards, but it is fast enough to cover the 5.6
mile route in less than 20 minutes. This is barely enough time to buy a latte,
turn on the cell phone and open up the computer. That is, a faster trip will
not be any more saleable than the proposed 20-minute timing.
Fig A-5 The proposed conceptual ferry design
More
important is efficient ticketing and very fast loading and unloading. This will
have a greater effect on trip time than a few knots of additional speed. This
requirement dictates the open side decks, in addition to the deck areas forward
and aft of the passenger cabin. Whether moored bow-in or on a side tie, there
will be deck area to accommodate multible gangways.
Low hull
volume also dictates the very wide beam, necessary to meet stability requirements.
Emissions
controls will be similar to those used on modern busses. Because of the low
speed, the horsepower per seat is comparable to that found on a city transit
bus.
Location of the terminal
This
proposal calls for a ferry service that more closely resembles the service of
100 years ago. Rather than use the existing ferry dock inside the Marina, there
would be a new terminal in the open water alongside the Berkeley Fishing Pier.
This location has several compelling advantages:
1) It is
the closest to San Francisco. The 5.6-mile route will only take 20 minutes at a
modest speed of 17 knots. This is about a mile closer than other suggested locations
at the foot of Gilman Street or Fleming Point (behind the race track).
2) There
will be no wasted time maneuvering in and out of the Marina.
3) Little
or no dredging is required, unlike the foot of Gilman Street or at Fleming
Point that would require extensive dredging projects.
4) The
Berkeley Pier is at the end of the AC Transit 51 M bus line. Because this is the terminus of a major
trunk line, there is very frequent service (about every 20 minutes all day),
yet ridership is low because it is near the end of the line. It is a natural
location for an intermodal transfer. Rather than requiring new bus service,
this location would make use of existing excess capacity at the end of an
existing route.
5) There
are 410 parking spaces in the parking lot serving Hs. Lordships restaurant and
along Seawall Drive south of the Pier. These are mostly unused during the week.
Other overflow parking areas are nearby in the Marina. Peak demand hours for
ferry parking generally miss the peak demand periods for Marina parking, so
this would also take advantage of existing infrastructure rather than requiring
new facilities.
6) There is
existing nearby commercial activity (unlike the proposed Gilman Street
location, where commercial development is in question). Commercial activity
makes the ferry terminal a more attractive place to wait or to meet, and the
presence of the ferry is likely to increase public revenue from the nearby
businesses.
7) The
ferry route would not have to traverse any part of the Eastshore State Park.
Sierra Club and other groups have opposed commuter ferry service to any
location in Berkeley or Albany on the grounds that it would not be compatible
with the Eastshore State Park. The Berkeley Pier location is furthest from the
park boundaries, and does not traverse any park tidelands.
Figure A-6 The East Bay shoreline in 1883, showing the
ferry terminal at Jacob's Landing at the foot of University Avenue.
The Politics
The Sierra
Club is on record as strongly opposing a commuter ferry operating from anywhere
along the Berkeley or Albany waterfront. This opposition appears to be based
primarily on the prospect of a larger and faster ferry operating from the foot
of Gilman Street, an area that the Sierra Club hopes will eventually be
acquired by the State and become part of the Eastshore State Park.
These
considerations should have no relevance to the this proposal, which is well
removed from the Eastshore State Park land and tidelands.
Sierra Club
has, however, raised the objection to ferry-related traffic transiting the
Eastshore State Park on University Avenue. The numbers, however, don't support
the claim that this would cause a detectable qualitative change in the traffic
level. With a maximum capacity of 149 passengers and three departures every
morning, it is hard to imagine how the four lanes of University Avenue would
become congested. Considered in the context of the number of seats in existing
waterfront restaurants, activities at other Marina businesses and offices, and
the number of boat berths served by those same roads, the traffic argument
becomes specious.
If we
conservatively assume a capacity of 500 cars per hour per lane, and three full
ferries with every seat representing another car, then we have only used 26
minutes of road capacity for the entire morning commute.
On the
other hand, several interest groups can be expected to offer strong support for
a Berkeley ferry.
The bicycle
groups - East Bay Bicycle Coalition and Bicycle Friendly Berkeley - are ferry
advocates. BART is closed to bicycles during commute hours, while a ferry with
a large bicycle deck promises the efficiency of a true dual mode
personal/public transportation system.
Handicapped
advocacy groups are expected to show favorable interest. Ferries are spacious
and easy to use, and offer safe mobility for people with a wide range of
disabilities.
People who
like to travel with their dogs are likely to be strong ferry advocates. There
is no reason to preclude dogs from the outside deck areas of a ferry operating
on a short route.
As we have
seen from various public planning processes, the combination of bicycles, dogs,
and the handicapped comprises a formidable lobbying force. Even in Berkeley,
the Sierra Club would be ill advised to oppose it.
The Fare Structure
If we make
some very conservative assumptions about costs, the back-of-the-envelope
economic analysis suggests that the required break-even no-subsidy ticket price
is $6.28 each way. This covers vessel construction and operation, and assumes
2/3 full on the forward commute, 1/3 full on the reverse commute, seven round
trips per day, and about $400/hour for total operating expenses.
$6.28 is
steep, but this is less than the ticket price on the Vallejo ferries and comparable
to the $6.75 charged for the Sausalito and Tiburon ferries. It compares very favorably
with the cost of parking in downtown San Francisco for the day, or the cost of
a trip on an airport shuttle. As long as the boat is small and the service is
not too ambitious, there is probably a sustainable market at this price point.
However,
the market-rate ticket exposes the ferry proposal to charges of elitism, and
the criticism that the service is designed to serve only the rich. There is
some truth to these charges, so the strategy proposed here is to implement a
policy analogous to that in effect on the major toll bridges. On the bridges,
carpools go free. The rationale for this policy is that they tread lightly on
both the environment and the transportation infrastructure, and help alleviate
the congestion of single-occupancy vehicles.
On the
ferry, anyone arriving by bicycle and bringing it aboard would ride free. The
rationale is the same as on the bridges. This would insure that the ferry
remains accessible to the widest possible range of income levels, without
relying on public funds or complicated and inefficient subsidy schemes. It
would also immensely simplify ticketing and boarding for bicyclists.
This scheme
is of course experimental, and its success would depend on both its popularity
and the level of abuse that could not be prevented by the obvious
countermeasures. The free ride might have to be replaced by a deep discount
after some operational experience is obtained.
Discounts
would also be offered for the "reverse" commuters, SF to Berkeley in
the morning and westbound in the afternoon. Parking is scarce and expensive at
the San Francisco ferry terminal, so the discount could be justified on similar
environmental/infrastructure grounds, if not on simple supply and demand.
Reverse commute discounts would be extremely valuable to a significant number
of students at U.C. Berkeley, as well as some City employees
The Schedule
Because of
the low subsidy level, the schedule must be driven by cost and revenue
considerations. As long as there is a place to park at BART, the ferry can
never hope to compete with BART for level of service as measured in convenient
access to the terminals or stations.
But BART
parking lots fill up early in the morning. They are generally full by 8:00 am
on weekdays. Although a small number of spaces become available at 10:00, and
can be reliably accessed between 10:00 and 10:05, for all practical purposes
BART is not an easy option after 8:00 am. Certainly there are many people who
can walk, bike, or bus to the BART station. And while we acknowledge that these
people hold the moral high ground, for the majority of riders the only viable
means of travel to the station is access by private auto.
There is no
point, then, in scheduling a ferry departure before 8:00 am. With 20 minute
transit time an hourly schedule is feasible using one boat, so the proposed
morning departures would be at 8, 9, and 10.
After the
10 am departure it is assumed that the demand will fall below the level that
would support an hourly schedule. The problem becomes one of keeping the boat
busy during the mid-day lull. Assuming the crew's work day has started at 7:30,
the crew has only been on watch for three hours when the ferry is finished
unloading at the Ferry Building at 10:30.
We propose
the route topology shift from part of the 'hub and spokes" system centered
around SF to a circular route around the central bay, keeping the legs short
enough to be compatible with the relatively slow speed.
After
leaving the Ferry Building, the ferry would begin a clockwise circuit to
Sausalito, Tiburon, Larkspur and Richmond, returning to Berkeley in time for a 1:00
pm departure.
The next
loop would include a stop at Treasure Island, then SF, Sausalito, Tiburon,
Larkspur and Richmond, returning to Berkeley for a 4:30 pm departure.
The 4:30 pm
Berkeley departure would be in SF in time for a 5 pm return commuter run straight back to
Berkeley. Hourly departures would continue at 6, 7, and 8 pm.
The boat is
finished for the evening at 8:30 pm, and the crew could probably punch out at
9. This is a 13.5 hour day, presumably done as one 7:30 am 1:00 pm shift of 5.5 hours, and one 1:00 pm
- 9:00 pm shift of eight hours.
The mid-day
circular routes provide one trip from the East Bay to Treasure Island, and two
trips each to the three terminals in Marin. This would fill an important gap in
transit mobility, as there is currently no easy way to travel from the East Bay
to Marin.
Note that
there are four evening commuter return trims, but only three morning trips.
This apparent imbalance is to account for two factors: 1) a significant number of
morning commuters will be pulled away by informal carpools, attracted to the
HOV lane to the Bay Bridge. Although other transit agencies have resisted and
discouraged this practice, the ferry service should recognize the value of the
informal carpool phenomenon and accommodate it as much as possible. 2) There is
typically a much wider distribution of return times than departure times.
People work late, run errands, and have other reasons to delay their return
trip, suggesting the four-trip three-hour return window.
Here is
what the tabulated schedule might look like:
Treasure San
Berkeley
Island Francisco Sausalito
Tiburon Larkspur Richmond Berkeley
8:00 8:30 9:00
9:00 9:30 10:00
10:00
10:30 11:00 11:30
12:00 12:30 1:00
1:00 1:30 2:00 2:30 3:00
3:30 4:00 4:30
4:30 5:00 5:30
5:30 6:00 6:30
6:30 7:00 7:30
7:30 8:00 8:30
On the
other hand, the public might be better served by a simpler schedule, with
hourly service all day:
Berkeley
San Francisco Berkeley
8:00 8:30 9:00
9:00 9:30 10:00
10:00
10:30 11:00
11:00
11:30 12:00
12:00 12:30 1:00
1:00 1:30 2:00
2:00 2:30 3:00
3:00 3:30 4:00
4:00 4:30 5:00
5:00 5:30 6:00
6:00 6:30 7:00
7:00 7:30 8:00
Economics
Assumptions:
First cost
of ferry: $4 million (very conservative - other estimates are below $1.5 million
for a ferry that meets these capacity and speed specifications).
Operating
cost (crew, fuel, maintenance, admin): $400/hour (also conservative, probably based
on a crew of three).
Port fees
in San Francisco: $20,000/year.
Terminal
construction in Berkeley: $2 million (this is a wild guess, but probably
conservative if no breakwater construction is required).
Occupancy:
2/3 capacity
(99) full fare passengers on seven forward commutes.
1/3 capacity
(50) full fare passengers on seven reverse commutes.
1/3 capacity
(50) full fare passengers on one mid-day circle route.
12.5
operating hours/day, 255 commute days/year.
Calculations:
Total
fares/year = 255 x (149 x 7 x 2/3 + 149 x 7 x 1/3 + 149 x 1/3)
=
278,630 full fares/year.
Capitalization
= $6 million x 0.1 = $600,000/year.
Operation =
255 x 12.5 x 400 + $20,000 = $1,150,000/year.
Total =
$1,750,000/year.
Required
fare for unsubsidized break-even = $1,750,000/278,630
= $6.28.
Closing quote
"Nothing is impossible for the man who
doesn't have to do it himself."
A.H. Weiler